Seat bias

Metric for fairness of apportionment methods

Seat bias is a property describing methods of apportionment. These are methods used to allocate seats in a parliament among federal states or among political parties. A method is biased if it systematically favors small parties over large parties, or vice versa. There are several mathematical measures of bias, which can disagree slightly.

Notation

There is a positive integer h {\displaystyle h} (=house size), representing the total number of seats to allocate. There is a positive integer n {\displaystyle n} representing the number of parties to which seats should be allocated. There is a vector of fractions ( t 1 , , t n ) {\displaystyle (t_{1},\ldots ,t_{n})} with i = 1 n t i = 1 {\displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{n}t_{i}=1} , representing entitlements - t i {\displaystyle t_{i}} represents the entitlement of party i {\displaystyle i} , that is, the fraction of seats to which i {\displaystyle i} is entitled (out of the total of h {\displaystyle h} ). This is usually the fraction of votes that this party has won in the elections.

The goal is to find an apportionment method is a vector of integers a 1 , , a n {\displaystyle a_{1},\ldots ,a_{n}} with i = 1 n a i = h {\displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{n}a_{i}=h} , called an apportionment of h {\displaystyle h} , where a i {\displaystyle a_{i}} is the number of seats allocated to party i.

An apportionment method is a multi-valued function M ( t , h ) {\displaystyle M(\mathbf {t} ,h)} , which takes as input a vector of entitlements and a house-size, and returns as output an apportionment of h {\displaystyle h} .

Pairwise comparison of methods

We say that an apportionment method M {\displaystyle M'} favors small parties more than M {\displaystyle M} if, for every t and h, and for every a M ( t , h ) {\displaystyle \mathbf {a'} \in M'(\mathbf {t} ,h)} and a M ( t , h ) {\displaystyle \mathbf {a} \in M(\mathbf {t} ,h)} , t i < t j {\displaystyle t_{i}<t_{j}} implies either a i a i {\displaystyle a_{i}'\geq a_{i}} or a j a j {\displaystyle a_{j}'\leq a_{j}} .

If M {\displaystyle M} and M {\displaystyle M'} are two divisor methods with divisor functions d {\displaystyle d} and d {\displaystyle d'} , and d ( a ) / d ( b ) > d ( a ) / d ( b ) {\displaystyle d'(a)/d'(b)>d(a)/d(b)} whenever a > b {\displaystyle a>b} , then M {\displaystyle M'} favors small agents more than M {\displaystyle M} .[1]: Thm.5.1  Therefore, Adams' method favors small parties more than Dean's, more than Hill's, more than Webster's, more than Jefferson's.

This fact can be expressed using the majorization ordering on integer vectors. A vector a seats majorizes another vector b, if for all k, the k largest parties receive in a at least as many seats as they receive in b. An apportionment method M {\displaystyle M} majorizes another method M {\displaystyle M'} , if for any house-size and entitlement-vector, M ( t , h ) {\displaystyle M(\mathbf {t} ,h)} majorizes M ( t , h ) {\displaystyle M'(\mathbf {t} ,h)} . If M {\displaystyle M} and M {\displaystyle M'} are two divisor methods with divisor functions d {\displaystyle d} and d {\displaystyle d'} , and d ( a ) / d ( b ) > d ( a ) / d ( b ) {\displaystyle d'(a)/d'(b)>d(a)/d(b)} whenever a > b {\displaystyle a>b} , then M {\displaystyle M'} majorizes M {\displaystyle M} . Therefore, Adams' is majorized by Dean's, majorized by Hill's, majorized by Webster's, majorized by Jefferson's.[2]

The shifted-quota method (largest-remainders method) with quota q i = t i ( h + s ) {\displaystyle q_{i}=t_{i}\cdot (h+s)} are also ordered by majorization, where methods with smaller s are majorized by methods with larger s.[2]

Counting over all house sizes

To measure the bias of a certain apportionment method M, one can check, for each pair of entitlements t 1 , t 2 {\displaystyle t_{1},t_{2}} , the set of all possible apportionments yielded by M, for all possible house sizes. Theoretically, the number of possible house sizes is infinite, but since t 1 , t 2 {\displaystyle t_{1},t_{2}} are usually rational numbers, it is sufficient to check the house sizes up to the product of their denominators. For each house size, one can check whether a 1 / t 1 > a 2 / t 2 {\displaystyle a_{1}/t_{1}>a_{2}/t_{2}} or a 1 / t 1 < a 2 / t 2 {\displaystyle a_{1}/t_{1}<a_{2}/t_{2}} . If the number of house-sizes for which a 1 / t 1 > a 2 / t 2 {\displaystyle a_{1}/t_{1}>a_{2}/t_{2}} equals the number of house-sizes for which a 1 / t 1 < a 2 / t 2 {\displaystyle a_{1}/t_{1}<a_{2}/t_{2}} , then the method is unbiased. The only unbiased method, by this definition, is Webster's method.[1]: Prop.5.2 

Averaging over all entitlement-pairs

One can also check, for each pair of possible allocations a 1 , a 2 {\displaystyle a_{1},a_{2}} , the set of all entitlement-pairs t 1 , t 2 {\displaystyle t_{1},t_{2}} for which the method M yields the allocations a 1 , a 2 {\displaystyle a_{1},a_{2}} (for h = a 1 + a 2 {\displaystyle h=a_{1}+a_{2}} ). Assuming the entitlements are distributed uniformly at random, one can compute the probability that M favors state 1 vs. the probability that it favors state 2. For example, the probability that a state receiving 2 seats is favored over a state receiving 4 seats is 75% for Adams, 63.5% for Dean, 57% for Hill, 50% for Webster, and 25% for Jefferson.[1]: Prop.5.2  The unique proportional divisor method for which this probability is always 50% is Webster.[1]: Thm.5.2  There are other divisor methods yielding a probability of 50%, but they do not satisfy the criterion of proportionality as defined in the "Basic requirements" section above. The same result holds if, instead of checking pairs of agents, we check pairs of groups of agents.[1]: Thm.5.3 

Averaging over all entitlement-vectors

One can also check, for each vector of entitlements (each point in the standard simplex), what is the seat bias of the agent with the k-th highest entitlement. Averaging this number over the entire standard simplex gives a seat bias formula.

Stationary divisor methods

For each stationary divisor method, i.e. one where a {\displaystyle a} seats correspond to a divisor d ( a ) = a + r {\displaystyle d(a)=a+r} , and electoral threshold t {\displaystyle t} :[3]: Sub.7.10 

MeanBias ( r , k , t ) = ( r 1 / 2 ) ( i = k n ( 1 / i ) 1 ) ( 1 n t ) {\displaystyle {\text{MeanBias}}(r,k,t)=(r-1/2)\cdot \left(\sum _{i=k}^{n}(1/i)-1\right)\cdot (1-nt)}

In particular, Webster's method is the only unbiased one in this family. The formula is applicable when the house size is sufficiently large, particularly, when h 2 n {\displaystyle h\geq 2n} . When the threshold is negligible, the third term can be ignored. Then, the sum of mean biases is:

k = 1 n MeanBias ( r , k , 0 ) ( r 1 / 2 ) ( n / e 1 ) {\displaystyle \sum _{k=1}^{n}{\text{MeanBias}}(r,k,0)\approx (r-1/2)\cdot (n/e-1)} , when the approximation is valid for n 5 {\displaystyle n\geq 5} .

Since the mean bias favors large parties when r > 1 / 2 {\displaystyle r>1/2} , there is an incentive for small parties to form party alliances (=coalitions). Such alliances can tip the bias in their favor. The seat-bias formula can be extended to settings with such alliances.[3]: Sub.7.11 

For shifted-quota methods

For each shifted-quota method (largest-remainders method) with quota q i = t i ( h + s ) {\displaystyle q_{i}=t_{i}\cdot (h+s)} , when entitlement vectors are drawn uniformly at random from the standard simplex,

MeanBias ( s , k , t ) = s n ( i = k n ( 1 / i ) 1 ) ( 1 n t ) {\displaystyle {\text{MeanBias}}(s,k,t)={\frac {s}{n}}\cdot \left(\sum _{i=k}^{n}(1/i)-1\right)\cdot (1-nt)}

In particular, Hamilton's method is the only unbiased one in this family.[3]

Real-world data

In addition to theoretical analysis, one can check the actual bias of a method in real-world distributions. Using United States census data, Balinski and Young found Webster's method to be the least median-biased estimator for comparing pairs of states, followed closely by the Huntington-Hill technique.[1] However, Ernst (1994) found that when using other definitions of bias, the Huntington-Hill method can also be described as least biased.[4]

References

  1. ^ a b c d e f Balinski, Michel L.; Young, H. Peyton (1982). Fair Representation: Meeting the Ideal of One Man, One Vote. New Haven: Yale University Press. ISBN 0-300-02724-9.
  2. ^ a b Pukelsheim, Friedrich (2017), Pukelsheim, Friedrich (ed.), "Preferring Stronger Parties to Weaker Parties: Majorization", Proportional Representation: Apportionment Methods and Their Applications, Cham: Springer International Publishing, pp. 149–157, doi:10.1007/978-3-319-64707-4_8, ISBN 978-3-319-64707-4, retrieved 2021-09-01
  3. ^ a b c Pukelsheim, Friedrich (2017), Pukelsheim, Friedrich (ed.), "Favoring Some at the Expense of Others: Seat Biases", Proportional Representation: Apportionment Methods and Their Applications, Cham: Springer International Publishing, pp. 127–147, doi:10.1007/978-3-319-64707-4_7, ISBN 978-3-319-64707-4, retrieved 2021-09-01
  4. ^ Ernst, Lawrence R. (1994). "Apportionment Methods for the House of Representatives and the Court Challenges". Management Science. 40 (10): 1207–1227. ISSN 0025-1909.